Whither Democracy in Canada?
Notes for Talk by Hon. David Kilgour, MP
Edmonton-Mill Woods-Beaumont
Democracy Now, Edmonton Chapter
University of Alberta Law School
Edmonton
16 March 2005
A representative democracy is supposed to function
as a means for the nationals of a country to voice their opinions and concerns.
MP’s, MLA’s etc are elected by constituents to represent their interests. They
can only maintain legitimacy by acting in accordance with the wishes of their
electorate most, if not all of the time.
In our
current electoral system, the ability of an elected official in government to
represent constituents is seriously impaired by the high degree of party
discipline prevalent in the Canadian system since about 1900. Some degree of
party discipline is necessary in order to maintain the coherence of political
parties as viable institutions; this should not preclude an elected person’s
ability to represent their constituents.
Currently, the role of the member as a representative is seriously compromised
by the fact that the real political power lies with the Prime Minister of the
day. The Prime Minister has the power to dismiss a member of his caucus at any
time; to make all cabinet appointments, all appointments to the senate, to the
Supreme Court; all ambassadors to name but a few. The combination of the Prime
Minister’s explicit power to discipline through censure or expulsion; and the
implicit power to discipline through denial of cabinet appointments, or other
appointments creates an environment in which it is severely disadvantageous for
caucus members to deviate from any agenda set by the Prime Minister.
One
Attempt to Reduce Party Discipline
In
February of 2004, the rules on votes for Liberal MP’s were overhauled and a
“line” voting system was put in place. It categorizes all votes as one, two or
three line votes. One-liners would be truly free votes, which would allow all
members, including cabinet members to vote as they see fit. Two-line votes would
compel cabinet members and relevant parliamentary secretaries to vote with the
government and encourage all other caucus members to do likewise. Three-line
votes are considered to be matters of confidence and would require all members
to vote with the government. Items such as the Throne Speech, the budget and
important supply motions are considered three-liners.
The aim
of the new system was to create more opportunity for free votes by making what
constitutes a matter of confidence, more explicit. Although the new system, in
theory allows for more free votes by increasing transparency with regard to
government prerogatives, the prime minister still holds the power to designate
what category a vote falls under on a vote-by-vote basis.
Thus the
new system does not change very much at all. A majority of votes under this new
system have been deemed two-line votes; and there have not been any truly free
votes to date.
Party
Expulsion In Practice
In the
case of three-line votes on which the ruling party decrees that all it’s members
must vote in favour, a member might be expelled for understandably following the
contrary wishes of their constituents. The threat of being expelled creates a
major dilemma for the MP or MLA whose greatest desire is to be faithful in their
service to their electorate.
An expelled MP is forced to sit as an independent
and is virtually excommunicated from the political process. He/she must try and
conduct their work with severely diminished resources and an extremely limited
procedural ability to ask a question or raise an issue in the House of Commons,
which diminishes their ability to serve their constituents. Such members have
little means of influencing government policy to the benefit of their
constituents in any way because they can no longer count of the support of their
former party. While true that any non-cabinet member has the right to put
forward a private member’s bill, this ability is of little practical value.
Private member’s bills are allocated a limited
amount of time for consideration and are generally prone to failure since they
require either the support of the governing party or broad-based support across
party lines in order to be passed. Consider here the fact that during the Thirty
Seventh Parliament out of the 880 private members’ bills tabled only eleven
substantive bills (those bills which are not merely name changes) received royal
assent. None of these bills had any significant socio-economic impact.
It is
very difficult for an MP to vote against any piece of government legislation
that the governing party has designated as a matter of confidence even though
one’s constituents are not in favour of it. One is faced with a choice in which
their ability to serve as representative is undermined regardless of what
choices they made. If one toes the party line on a piece of legislation their
constituents have deemed undesirable, you lose the faith and trust of their
electors and are seen as a political figure that lacks legitimacy. If one obeys
the wishes of their constituents, one’s ability to serve them becomes severely
constrained as a result of being dismissed from their political party.
Trumping Public Opinion
The
reality of our present system is that the will of the constituents is often
“trumped” by party discipline. Ironically, members of the governing party, who
should theoretically be in a good position to serve the interests of their
constituents, are in practice the least empowered.
Inter-Party Cooperation
Another
important consequence of the current system is that it often effectively closes
the door to any sort of cooperative efforts in the policy-making realm among
parties. Where parties dominate the process as they do now, there is no real
forum for substantive policy dialogue to take place among members of different
parties when one has a majority.
One may
contend that Question Period serves such a role, but Q.P. can hardly be seen as
a constructive policy forum. It is pointless for a member of any party to try
and lobby members of other parties during Q.P. given the reality that virtually
every vote will result in each party’s respective members voting with their
party in the majority of cases. The lobbying that goes on in the House of
Commons is really directed toward the public as parties jockey for position in
anticipation of the next election.
In the U.S., where certainly there is a constitutional separation of powers
between the executive and the legislative branches of government, laws are
passed with far less party discipline. The separation of powers and the weakness
of party discipline in voting on Capitol Hill greatly facilitate effective
regional representation in Washington. Unlike the situation in Canada where a
government falls if it loses the support of a majority in the House on a
confidence vote, U.S. presidents and congress are elected for fixed terms.
Neither resigns if a measure of any kind is voted down in either the Senate or
the House of Representatives.
The voting practices in our two countries are so different that The
Congressional Quarterly defines party unity votes as those in which at least
51 per cent of members of one party vote against 51 per cent of the other party.
Under this definition, itself astonishing to Canadian legislators, the
Quarterly notes that for the years 1975-1982 party unity votes occurred in
only 44.2 per cent of the 4,417 recorded Senate votes and in only 39.8 per cent
of those in the House of Representatives. This sample, moreover, includes the
years 1976-1980, the last period before 1992-96 when Democrats controlled the
White House and both branches of Congress.
Regional Block Voting
Another feature of the American system that fosters effective regional input in
national policymaking is territorial bloc voting - something quite unknown in
Canada's House of Commons. Representatives from both political parties from the
Mountain, Sun Belt, New England and others regions vote en bloc or work together
in committees to advance common regional interests.
A good example of how effective regional representatives can influence the
geographic location of federal government procurement, which affects the
geographic distribution of the manufacturing sector, is the Southern influence
in Congress. It played a major role in the post-war concentration of federal
military and space expenditures in the South and in the general economic revival
and growth of the Sun Belt. During 1981-82, for example, the height of the
"boll-weevil era", the long-time legislative coalition of Southern Democrats and
Republicans was successful more than 85 per cent of the time, due to mutual
areas of agreement and interest.
The point of this comparison is only to emphasize
that, unlike the American Congress, Canadian bloc voting makes bi- or
tri-partisan agreement on anything in our legislatures except in minority
government situations, exceedingly rare. In our current political culture, if a
government or opposition MP’s loyalty to his/her province clashes with the
instruction of the party whip, placing constituent or regional considerations
first voting implies considerable risk to one's prospects for party advancement.
Private MPs in Canada are thus far less able to
represent regional interests effectively than are their counterparts in
Washington, where there is freedom allowing effective regional representation
when an issue has clear regional implications.
This, of course, is not to suggest that Canada
should duplicate the American style of government. It is to point out that the
best solution to ongoing problems of representative democracy in Canada might be
to adapt attractive features from various systems, including the American one.
Another system useful to examine is that of
Germany. In Germany a vote of non-confidence requires that the opposition, on
the same motion also propose a candidate of their own whom they wish to be
appointed Chancellor by the Federal President. A motion of non-confidence is
required to be made at the same time as one for a new Chancellor. The idea
behind this structure was to prevent crises by always maintaining a Chancellor
in office. Unlike Canada’s current application of the Westminster model, the
Chancellor does not resign upon the passage of a non-confidence motion and must
instead be dismissed by the Federal President. To put this into a Canadian
context, in the case of the Clark government as an example, the defeat of the
government’s budget in December 1979 would not have ousted Clark from office
unless the Liberals, New Democrats and Social Credit MPs had agreed
simultaneously on a new prime minister who could hold the confidence of a
majority of MPs. The adoption of a similar measure in our own practices would
weaken party discipline and facilitate greater independence for MP’s to vote on
the merits of issues without fear of toppling a government.
Revitalization of Canadian
Democracy
The democratic deficit in Canada is clearly in
need of some work when one examines the long-term trends in participation rates.
Voter turnout has been steadily trending downward over the last two decades from
an average of 75% between 1945 and 1988. Since then, it was recorded at 61.2%
for the 2001 election and reached an all time low of 60.5% for the 2004 election
despite the fact that it was hotly contested. As Carty, Cross and Young noted in
Rebuilding Canadian Party Politics:
“Public opinion and survey data confirm that at
the outset of the new century large numbers of Canadians continue to believe
their politicians and political institutions are out of touch and unresponsive,
and are increasingly dissatisfied with the performance of parliament and
political parties.”
This is
borne out in a poll Pollara conducted in 2003, which showed that 74% of
respondents agreed with the statement “Generally, those elected to Parliament
soon lose touch with the people”. Fully 67% agreed that, “People like me don’t
have any say about what government does.” If we are to continue to have a
vibrant democracy in Canada it is clear that the relaxation of party discipline
and the facilitation of greater opportunities for free votes will go a long way
toward increasing the degree of engagement that Canadian citizens now have with
the political process.
Canadians will feel that our elected representatives have a greater degree of
accountability toward them as opposed to their party if a member is empowered by
having the ability to vote in ways that accord with the wishes of their
constituents on a regular basis. This will be an important step in reversing
voter apathy. Increased accountability of MP’s to constituents will increase the
degree of engagement Canadians have with the political process; it will
encourage them to get more involved not only at election times but in between as
well.
Canada
is a federal state and federalism means that on some issues the will of the
popular majority will be frustrated. If the biggest battalions of voters are to
prevail over smaller ones under any circumstances, we should drop the charade
that we have a federal system of government that respects minorities in times of
stress. The notion that the largest group of Canadians, i.e., southern Ontarians
and metropolitan Quebeckers, must be accommodated always has resulted in
discontent everywhere and accompanying feelings of regional subordinancy.
Putting Constituents First
In an
increasingly interdependent world, many Canadians in our outer eight provinces
and territories at least want new or altered institutions that will represent
the interest of both "Inner Canadians" (those who live in the
Toronto-Ottawa-Montreal corridor) and "Outer Canadians" effectively. Unless we
move away from the notion that "the national interest" is merely a code-phrase
for the most populous region dominating all corners of the country, frictions
between Inner and Outer Canada are likely to remain and worsen.
If party
discipline is relaxed, representation for all areas of Canada would be improved.
It would be easier for, say, Western MPs to defy their party establishments, if
need be, in support of Western issues. Coalitions composed of members of all
parties could exist for the purpose of working together on issues of common
regional or other concern. The present adversarial attitudes and structures of
Parliament or legislatures in which opposition parties oppose virtually anything
a government proposes might change in the direction of all parties working
together for the national good.
At
present, few government and opposition MPs have any real opportunity to put
constituents first in votes in the House of Commons. Real power is concentrated
in the hands of the three party leaderships. Canadian democracy itself would
benefit if we put our present mind-numbing party discipline where it belongs -
in the history books.
|